Electricity’s un-natural monopoly is about to end

ILSR

luxury-tax-monopoly-flickr-Philip-Taylor-320x240The U.S. electricity system is undergoing the biggest change in its 130-year history, undermining the rationale for monopoly ownership and control.

Until recently, electricity service was similar to water or roads, where a natural monopoly was most efficient. Only a single, standardized electric grid was needed to connect each building. Technology options were limited to steam-powered turbines fueled by coal and oil, or large hydro dams with massive economies of scale. There was very little long-distance transmission of power, as each utility was responsible for electricity service within its own territory. Growth in demand was exploding and monopoly utilities could wield the most cost-effective financing for new power plants. These natural monopolies paid off for customers, with falling costs of reliable electricity even as demand rose rapidly.

But the 21st century electricity system is radically different.

The scale of electricity generation is rapidly shrinking, from coal and nuclear power plants that can power a million homes to solar and wind power plants that power a few to a few hundred nearby homes. Electricity demand has leveled off, so that every unit of new wind and solar power produced for the grid displaces a unit of fossil fuel energy. Batteries and electric vehicles provide new tools for distributed energy storage. Smartphones and smart appliances are giving electricity customers unprecedented opportunities to manage their energy use.*

It no longer makes sense to preserve last century’s forms of utility ownership and control in a century where cost-effective technology enables widely distribution production and ownership of electricity. And yet, a majority of state laws governing electricity service still preserve this monopoly model. Even those that do not have made little progress on democratizing the electricity system.

Incremental Changes

There have been incremental changes. In the last three decades of the 20th Century, federal regulators opened the utility market to competition from non-utility generators who used higher efficiency or renewable-fueled power plants and opened the wholesale market to competition by making the transmission system a common carrier. These moves showed that utilities did not have a natural monopoly over power generation and emphasized the public nature of the grid infrastructure by allowing fair and non-discriminatory access. Competition was introduced between big players who could own and operate large power plants.

Changes in the 1990s also introduced retail sales “competition” that proved elusive. California’s near-bankruptcy due to price manipulation by Enron and others led many states to freeze or reverse retail deregulation. Even in states where retail competition has been maintained, public advocates warn it has offered little innovation in electricity service (other than promotional rates like offered by the cable industry). More to the point, retail competition does little to empower electric users, who are still just consumers of power.

The most potent change has been the growth of conservation and energy efficiency. These tools offer non-utility and cost-effective alternatives to new power plants, and as such, illustrate the unnatural nature of utility monopolies. Many states have shifted to independent, non-utility delivery of conservation and energy efficiency services (e.g. Efficiency Vermont).

rsz_beyond-utility-20-to-energy-democracy-graphics-ilsr003

Retaining Market Power

At the present, however, utilities still maintain monopoly or exercise market power over many aspects of the grid. On the transmission system, for example, planning rules make it very difficult to implement less costly, non power line alternatives to utility power line proposals (see Beyond Utility 2.0 to Energy Democracy, p21). In particular, planning is rarely integrated with distribution level planning, where distribution energy generation (like solar) can serve reliability and energy needs. Distribution planning also suffers from utility monopoly, because as utility expert and former utility manager Karl Rabago says, “utilities simply do not think things they do not own or control can be resources.” Thus, system planning rarely incorporates customer-owned solar, electric vehicles, energy storage, and many other cost-effective strategies for meeting electricity needs.

In other words, the natural monopoly has become unnatural, with utility managers wedded to costly legacy infrastructure solutions (like poles and wires) in an era of remarkable local and non-utility resources.  New utility power plants and power lines will last for 40-50 years, but distributed energy resources will be competitive well within the lifetime of these legacy investments. For example, by 2022, on-site solar power could provide less costly electricity than the electric utility for at least 10% of residential and commercial customers in nearly every state. In that timeframe, electric vehicles and other energy storage options combined with powerful “apps” will give utility customers unprecedented control over their energy use.

Replacing an Unnatural Monopoly

Monopoly is no longer natural or even cost effective. But what will replace it?

For one, it must be a grid built on the principles of a 21st century electricity system. I offer five pillars of a Utility 3.0 model, or energy democracy. Three of these derive from the prominent Utility 2.0 conversation.

rsz_beyond-utility-20-to-energy-democracy-graphics-ilsr027

How will these principles be applied to the end of the natural utility monopoly?

On the transmission system, there’s a clear need for policy to re-integrate planning with the local level, where there are many more opportunities for conservation, efficiency, and distributed energy to meet regional needs than ever before. There are a few other suggestions, for federal regulators, in this post.

On the distribution system, the answer is new management and, likely, ownership. The New York Public Service Commission’s Reforming the Energy Vision process has already outlined a plan for an independent manager for the distribution system, but it may fall short of the necessary steps to make the distribution system a tool for energy democracy.

Until the turn of the 21st century, the distribution system was simply the last mile of lines bringing power one-way from utility operated power plants to customers. But now the distribution system can facilitate energy democracy. Individual and community solar arrays can produce local electricity; electric vehicles, energy storage, and smart appliances can manage energy use; networked thermostats and smartphone apps can give individuals and businesses unprecedented power as energy managers. The following graphic provides a very simplified picture.

rsz_beyond-utility-20-to-energy-democracy-graphics-ilsr022

To facilitate this network, the distribution system needs to be a common carrier, with non-discriminatory access to all. But the infrastructure of the local grid (substations, transformers, etc) also has to be vastly upgraded and smartened to enable local ownership and management of energy systems, and the transactions between these local owners. These investments, in the public interest and not the manager’s interest, necessitate complete separation from utility ownership and management as long as utility’s still have a vested financial interest in particular outcomes (e.g. a guaranteed rate of return from building new infrastructure). The grid could be owned as a commons, like the roads or municipal water supply, or not. But it must be built and operated to facilitate maximum economic opportunity for electric customers.

Maintaining an unnatural monopoly is inefficient, but failing to correct it is enormously costly. Energy efficiency and distributed energy offer electricity customers $48 billion economic opportunity, and the rules for the electricity system should allow them to seize control.

Source: ILSR. Reproduced with permission.

Comments

5 responses to “Electricity’s un-natural monopoly is about to end”

  1. coomadoug Avatar
    coomadoug

    If we move the wholesale electricity market to the other side of the meter into the home, it starts to fall into place because of the multiplication of opportunity for both customer and provider.

  2. daveletsgo Avatar
    daveletsgo

    Living in up-state NY we pay the highest rates in one of the worse economies in the country. National Greed or Grid however you say it allows in their monopoly for the consumer to buy from several vendors of the power. the monopoly lies in who delivers the juice. As they own the transmission lines. If your home goes unoccupied for the winter you get a maintence bill.

  3. jstack6 Avatar
    jstack6

    I have friends in Upstate NY (Skaneatleles) near where I lived (SYR) that are on GRID Tied Solar and National GRID owe’s them! Wind is also good and I think the best in that area is Geo-Thermal like Lemoyne College has had for about 10 years. It can cool or heat from ground temps of 68F all year.
    I now live in Phoenix AZ on Solar and my local power company also pays me since I help them. I make 110% of what I need.

  4. Chris Fraser Avatar
    Chris Fraser

    I suspect grids in densely populated areas will be desirable and marketable. A grid owned by a large body corporate will be efficient and have the option of self-managing or leasing the management role out to an experienced grid operator. The difference is this: It is democratic, the occupiers have a choice on how to manage it, from time to time, with the choice of changing responsibilities if they want to.The other side of this coin is energy supply in remote areas. Firstly, a question arises of how to deliver energy the most efficient way. Guess what .. it may not be via reticulation grids extending to the nether regions. Other options available due to technology changes now have to be considered.Then, although not as efficient as the Cities, the incumbent grid operator has to manage all the remote area assets. For energy price equity, this grid would have to be subsidised, but provides Cities a benefit in terms of access to remote area resources that Cities use.

  5. Todd McKissick Avatar
    Todd McKissick

    We don’t really need “managers”. All we need to do is mandate that all billing entities (i.e utility companies now) must break down their instantaneous prices for generation, transmission and distribution and then publish that price online. With this one piece in place, all appliances, distributed generation sources, storage facilities and any other devices that use or provide to the grid, can all migrate to more intelligent operation. As this market grows and predictive algorithms get better at predicting grid balance, the people with the smartest stuff will scream for the billing to reflect this instant price. And when that gets implemented, the adoption will grow rapidly. As this adoption of smart prediction takes over, the grid will balance itself, including transmission. Should prices begin to rise in an area, people will have more incentive to generate their own power, thus reducing either the generation or transmission that region was spending money on.

    The other side of this coin is that big factories which now get massively lower rates than residential customers will be seen for what they are – another corporate subsidy on the backs of the average homeowner.

Get up to 3 quotes from pre-vetted solar (and battery) installers.